
Predictably Irrational
10 minThe Hidden Forces That Shape Our Decisions
Introduction
Narrator: Imagine you’re browsing the website for The Economist magazine and come across a peculiar subscription offer. You have three choices: an internet-only subscription for $59, a print-only subscription for $125, or a combined print-and-internet subscription, also for $125. Which would you choose? The print-only option seems absurd; it’s the same price as the print-and-internet bundle. When behavioral economist Dan Ariely presented this to 100 MIT students, a predictable pattern emerged. No one chose the print-only option, but 84 students chose the combined package. However, when he removed the seemingly useless print-only "decoy" option, the results flipped dramatically. Now, 68 students chose the cheaper internet-only subscription. The decoy, which nobody wanted, was not useless at all; its mere presence was systematically changing people's decisions.
This is the central puzzle explored in Dan Ariely's groundbreaking book, Predictably Irrational: The Hidden Forces That Shape Our Decisions. Ariely argues that our decisions are not just irrational, but predictably so. By uncovering the hidden psychological forces at play, we can begin to understand why we splurge on a lavish meal but clip coupons for soup, and why a 50-cent aspirin can cure a headache that a one-cent aspirin cannot.
The Truth About Relativity
Key Insight 1
Narrator: Ariely demonstrates that humans rarely make choices in absolute terms. We lack an internal value meter to tell us what things are worth. Instead, we rely on context and comparison, focusing on the relative advantage of one thing over another. This is why the decoy option in The Economist experiment was so powerful. It made the print-and-internet bundle look like a fantastic deal in comparison to the print-only option, steering people away from the cheapest choice.
This principle is exploited everywhere. A restaurant consultant named Gregg Rapp advises clients to place a very high-priced entrée on the menu. While few people will order it, its presence makes the second-most expensive dish seem reasonably priced, boosting its sales and the restaurant's overall revenue. Similarly, when Williams-Sonoma first introduced a home bread-making machine for $275, sales were poor. Consumers had no context to judge its value. The company’s marketing firm then introduced a larger, more expensive model. Suddenly, sales of the original $275 machine took off. By providing a point of comparison, the company gave consumers the context they needed to feel they were making a smart purchase. This reliance on relativity means our choices can be easily manipulated by the options presented to us, often without our conscious awareness.
The Power of Arbitrary Anchors
Key Insight 2
Narrator: Our tendency to compare things leads to another peculiar behavior: anchoring. Ariely argues that our first decision in a new domain becomes an "anchor" that influences a long series of future decisions. In a famous experiment, he asked MIT students to write down the last two digits of their social security number. He then asked them if they would pay that amount for various items, like a bottle of wine or a cordless keyboard. Afterward, he held a real auction for those items.
The results were stunning. Students with high social security numbers, from 80 to 99, bid on average 216 to 346 percent more than those with low numbers, from 00 to 19. The social security number, a completely random and arbitrary figure, had become an anchor that powerfully influenced their willingness to pay. Ariely calls this "arbitrary coherence." While the initial prices are arbitrary, once they are set in our minds, they shape not only the present price but all future prices for similar items, creating a coherent, yet irrational, pattern. This is how the "pearl king" Salvador Assael transformed worthless Tahitian black pearls into a luxury good. By anchoring them next to the world's finest gems in the window of Harry Winston's store, he created a new, high-value anchor in the minds of consumers, and a new market was born.
The Seductive Pull of "FREE!"
Key Insight 3
Narrator: The word "free" holds a special, irrational power over the human mind. It’s not just another price; it’s an emotional hot button that can cause us to make poor decisions. To test this, Ariely and his colleagues offered people a choice between a high-quality Lindt truffle for 15 cents and a low-quality Hershey's Kiss for 1 cent. A strong majority, 73 percent, chose the superior truffle.
But when they dropped the price of each by just one cent, the results reversed. The Lindt truffle was now 14 cents, and the Hershey's Kiss was free. Suddenly, 69 percent of people chose the free Kiss. The one-cent difference between the prices was the same, but the introduction of "free" caused a massive shift in behavior. Ariely explains that when we are faced with a choice between a free item and a priced item, we often forget the downside. The emotional charge of getting something for nothing is so strong that we perceive the free item as immensely more valuable than it really is. This is because free items feel like they have no risk of loss, a powerful motivator that can cloud our judgment and lead us to choose an inferior option.
The Clash of Social and Market Norms
Key Insight 4
Narrator: We live in two different worlds, each governed by its own set of rules. One is the world of market norms, where exchanges are explicit and based on wages, prices, and costs. The other is the world of social norms, which is warm, fuzzy, and based on community and reciprocity. Problems arise when these two worlds collide.
Ariely illustrates this with a simple thought experiment: imagine you’ve just enjoyed a wonderful Thanksgiving dinner at your mother-in-law's house. As you're about to leave, you pull out your wallet and ask how much you owe her. The suggestion would be deeply offensive because it attempts to apply market norms to a social relationship. In an experiment, when lawyers were asked by the AARP to offer their services to needy retirees for a discounted rate of $30 per hour, they refused. But when they were asked to offer their services for free, they overwhelmingly agreed. The $30 offer was judged by market norms and found wanting, while the request to volunteer was judged by social norms and embraced. Ariely warns that once market norms enter a relationship, social norms are pushed out, and they are very difficult to reestablish.
The Danger of Making Decisions While Aroused
Key Insight 5
Narrator: We are all, in a sense, two different people: a rational, "cold state" Dr. Jekyll and an emotional, "hot state" Mr. Hyde. A central finding in Ariely's work is that we are terrible at predicting how we will behave in a hot state when we are currently in a cold one. To study this, Ariely and his colleagues conducted an experiment with male undergraduates at Berkeley. First, in a calm, rational state, they answered a series of questions about their sexual preferences and moral boundaries.
Then, they were asked to answer the same questions again while in a state of sexual arousal. The differences were profound. In their aroused state, the students' willingness to engage in morally questionable behavior and unsafe sexual practices skyrocketed. They were simply unable to predict the influence that passion would have on their decision-making. This disconnect explains why "just say no" campaigns often fail. They rely on the cold-state mind to control the hot-state body, a battle that reason often loses. The key, Ariely suggests, is to recognize our vulnerability in hot states and create systems and pre-commitments in our cold state to protect us from our future, irrational selves.
Conclusion
Narrator: The single most important takeaway from Predictably Irrational is that our irrational behaviors are neither random nor senseless. They are systematic, and because they are systematic, they are predictable. Standard economics assumes that we are rational actors who weigh the pros and cons of a choice and select the optimal path. Behavioral economics, in contrast, shows that we are far more complex, influenced by context, emotions, and hidden psychological forces.
The true power of Ariely's work lies in its practical application. By understanding the patterns of our irrationality—our susceptibility to decoys, our anchoring to arbitrary numbers, our love for "free"—we can begin to guard against them. The book offers what economists often say doesn't exist: a "free lunch." The knowledge itself is the tool. It allows us to design better environments, create more effective policies, and make more informed personal decisions. The ultimate challenge the book leaves us with is this: now that you can see the strings, can you learn to be a better puppeteer of your own life?