Aibrary Logo
Podcast thumbnail

The Tyrant's Toolkit

14 min

Why Bad Behavior is Almost Always Good Politics

Golden Hook & Introduction

SECTION

Michael: Everything you think you know about politics is probably wrong. We're taught it's about ideology—left versus right, capitalism versus socialism. Kevin: Yeah, it’s about values, right? What a country stands for. Michael: That's the story we're told. But what if the real game is much simpler, and much more cynical? What if every leader, from a US president to Kim Jong Un, follows the exact same, unwritten rulebook to get and keep power? Kevin: Okay, that's a bold claim. You're saying there's a universal playbook for power? Michael: That's the explosive premise of The Dictator's Handbook: Why Bad Behavior is Almost Always Good Politics by political scientists Bruce Bueno de Mesquita and Alastair Smith. Kevin: And these aren't just pundits. I read that Bueno de Mesquita is famous for a game theory model that's been used to forecast major political events, almost like a modern-day Nostradamus. So this isn't just opinion, it's based on a system. Michael: Exactly. They took decades of academic research on what they call 'selectorate theory' and boiled it down into a guide that is as insightful as it is unsettling. It's been called the modern-day version of Machiavelli's The Prince, and for good reason. It all starts with a simple, powerful idea that changes how you see everything. Kevin: I'm intrigued. And a little scared. Where do we start? Michael: We start by forgetting the labels we use, like 'democracies' and 'dictatorships'. According to the authors, to understand the real mechanics of power, you only need to look at three hidden groups of people that exist in any system of rule.

The Political Universe in Three Groups: The Selectorate Theory

SECTION

Kevin: Three hidden groups? That sounds like something out of a conspiracy movie. Michael: It feels like it, but it’s surprisingly logical. The first group is the Nominal Selectorate. This is everyone who theoretically has a say in choosing the leader. In the United States, that’s every eligible voter. In an autocracy like China, it might be every member of the Communist Party. It's the largest pool. Kevin: Okay, the pool of potential choosers. Got it. Michael: The second, smaller group is the Real Selectorate. These are the people who actually choose the leader. In the U.S., you could argue this is the people who actually show up to vote, especially in key primaries or swing states. They're the ones who really matter in picking the person. Kevin: So, the people with real influence. The voters who turn out, the party insiders, the influential delegates. Michael: Precisely. But here is the most important group, the one that the entire book hinges on: the Winning Coalition. This is the smallest group of all. They are the essential supporters whose backing a leader absolutely must have to keep power. If a leader loses them, they're out. Kevin: Hold on. So you’re saying a leader doesn't need to please all the voters, or even all the people who put them in power? They just need to keep this tiny 'winning coalition' happy? Michael: That is the central insight. The size of that winning coalition determines everything. Let's take a wild example from the book: the small town of Bell, California. In 2010, it was discovered that the city manager, Robert Rizzo, was paying himself nearly $800,000 a year, and the city council members were getting around $100,000 for part-time work. Kevin: In a small, poor town? How on earth did he get away with that? The voters must have been furious. Michael: They were, once they found out. But Rizzo didn't need the voters. The nominal selectorate was the 36,000 residents of Bell. The real selectorate was the few thousand who actually voted in obscure, off-cycle elections. But his winning coalition? It was just the handful of city council members he paid off. As long as their pockets were lined, they approved his salary and kept him in power. He only needed to keep them happy. Kevin: Wow. So he made his winning coalition tiny and paid them with public money. That's... brilliant and horrifying. It’s like a miniature dictatorship run on a city council level. Michael: Exactly. And this isn't new. The book argues that even supposedly 'absolute' monarchs were playing the same game. Take Louis XIV of France, the "Sun King." He famously said, "L'état, c'est moi"—"I am the state." Kevin: Right, the ultimate autocrat. He answered to no one. Michael: Not true. He inherited a court full of powerful, old-guard aristocrats who could challenge him. They were his inherited winning coalition. So what did he do? He built the Palace of Versailles and forced them all to live there. He made their income and status entirely dependent on his favor. He created a new class of nobles loyal only to him, and a professional army open to commoners. He systematically replaced his old winning coalition with a new one that he controlled completely. Kevin: So even the Sun King had a board of directors he had to manage. He just did it with palaces and patronage instead of stock options. This is a radical way to look at history. It’s not about divine right or ideology; it’s just about managing your key supporters. Michael: It applies everywhere. A CEO has a board of directors—that's their winning coalition. A startup founder has their key investors. A mob boss has his capos. The logic is universal. And once you understand that, the rules for staying in power become terrifyingly clear.

The 5 Rules of the Dictator's Handbook: A Cynic's Guide to Power

SECTION

Kevin: Okay, so if every leader just needs to keep this small 'winning coalition' happy, what's the playbook? How do they actually do it? This is the 'handbook' part, right? Michael: This is the handbook, and it's brutally pragmatic. The authors lay out five basic rules. Let's touch on a few of the most important ones. Rule number one is: Keep your winning coalition as small as possible. Kevin: Why small? Wouldn't you want more supporters? Michael: No, because a smaller coalition is cheaper. If you only need to keep five people loyal, you can give them immense rewards. If you need to keep five million people loyal, the rewards have to be spread thin, usually in the form of public goods like good roads or clean water, which are expensive and benefit everyone, not just your supporters. A dictator wants to concentrate rewards, not spread them. Kevin: That makes a chilling amount of sense. It’s cheaper to buy a few Ferraris than to build a national highway system. What's another rule? Michael: Rule number three is a big one: Control the flow of revenue. Power isn't just about armies; it's about cash. A leader needs money to pay their winning coalition. If you control the treasury, the oil fields, or the tax revenue, you control the rewards. Lose control of the money, and you lose your coalition. Kevin: This is why we see warlords fighting over diamond mines or oil fields. It's not for the country, it's to fund their payroll. Michael: Precisely. But the most shocking and important rule is Rule number five: Don't take money out of your supporters' pockets to make the people's lives better. Kevin: Wait, say that again. Michael: Don't take from your essential supporters to help the general population. If you have a choice between giving your coalition members a tax cut or funding a new hospital for the public, you give the tax cut. Every time. Helping the people at the expense of your coalition is political suicide. Kevin: That is the most cynical thing I have ever heard. It’s literally the opposite of Robin Hood. It’s the Sheriff of Nottingham's official guide to governance. Michael: It is. And leaders enforce this ruthlessly. The book gives the example of Saddam Hussein. Shortly after he took power in 1979, he called a meeting of the ruling Ba'ath Party leaders. He had one man come forward and "confess" to a plot against the state, and then read a list of 68 other "coconspirators" in the room. One by one, they were taken outside. Twenty-two were executed on the spot, by their fellow party members. Kevin: Oh my god. Why would he do that to his own supporters? Michael: Because he was pruning his coalition. He was getting rid of anyone who wasn't 100% loyal and sending a terrifying message to the survivors: "Your life and wealth depend entirely on me." The survivors were now an even smaller, more loyal, and more terrified winning coalition. He was following the rules. Kevin: But how does this apply in a democracy? Surely a president can't just do that. Michael: Of course not. The tools are different, but the logic can be similar. A democratic leader has a huge winning coalition—millions of voters. So they can't just hand out bags of cash. They have to rely on public goods: a strong economy, national security, good healthcare. But they still find ways to reward their specific coalitions. Think of gerrymandering, where politicians literally draw districts to create a safe winning coalition for themselves. Or pork-barrel spending, where a congressman gets a bridge built in his district. That's a private reward for his specific coalition of voters, paid for by all taxpayers. Kevin: So it's the same logic, just constrained by laws and a much, much bigger group of people you have to please. The scale is what saves us from the worst of it. Michael: Exactly. The size of the winning coalition is the key variable that separates a Switzerland from a North Korea. And that logic also explains why so many well-intentioned policies, like foreign aid, go so horribly wrong.

The Logic of Corruption: Why 'Good Intentions' Often Fail

SECTION

Michael: And that cynical logic of Rule 5, of rewarding your coalition at the expense of everyone else, perfectly explains why things like corruption and foreign aid often go so wrong. Kevin: How so? I always thought of corruption as a sign of a broken system. A bug. Michael: The book argues that in many systems, corruption isn't a bug; it's a feature. It's the primary way leaders pay their winning coalition. The leader allows their generals, ministers, and cronies to be corrupt, to skim from state-owned industries or take bribes. That's their private reward for staying loyal. Trying to stamp out corruption would be like a CEO suddenly cutting the board's salary. You’d be out of a job fast. Kevin: So it's a tool of governance. That reframes everything. It also helps explain the "Resource Curse." I've always wondered why so many countries that are rich in natural resources—oil, diamonds, minerals—have some of the poorest populations on earth. Michael: The theory explains it perfectly. Think of a country like Nigeria, with its vast oil wealth. The government's revenue comes from oil checks from international companies, not from taxing its people. So, does the leader need the people to be educated, healthy, and productive? Kevin: No. He doesn't need their labor or their tax money at all. He just needs to control the oil money. Michael: Exactly. So he uses that oil money to pay off his winning coalition—the military generals, the political elites—and he can completely ignore the needs of the 200 million other citizens. The country gets richer, but the people get poorer, because they are irrelevant to the leader's survival. The oil money breaks the link between a leader and their people. Kevin: And foreign aid... oh no. Let me guess. It works just like oil money. Michael: It's the exact same logic. When a wealthy country sends billions in aid to a nation run by a dictator, that money is a windfall. It's free revenue. The dictator doesn't have to answer to his people for it. He can use it to buy more loyalty from his coalition, strengthening his grip on power. Kevin: So when we send aid to a country run by a dictator, we're not helping the people, we're actually helping the dictator stay in power by giving him cash to pay off his supporters? That's a devastating thought. Michael: It's a central and controversial argument of the book. The authors show that aid often allows autocrats to avoid making necessary reforms. If they were broke, they might have to liberalize the economy and give people more freedom just to generate tax revenue. But with a steady flow of aid, they can just keep paying their cronies and oppressing everyone else. Kevin: That is deeply depressing. It feels like a catch-22. You want to help people suffering, but the very act of helping might be entrenching the person causing the suffering. Michael: It's a huge dilemma. The authors argue that the only aid that works is aid tied to concrete, structural changes. Not just promising to be less corrupt, but changing the rules of the game—like expanding who can vote, ensuring a free press, or making the political system more competitive. In other words, forcing the leader to enlarge their winning coalition.

Synthesis & Takeaways

SECTION

Kevin: So after all this... what's the big takeaway? Is it all just hopeless cynicism? It feels like a pretty bleak view of humanity. Michael: It is cynical, and the authors admit that. The book was widely seen as provocative when it came out in 2011, right in the middle of the Arab Spring, because it provided such a cold, mechanical explanation for why some of those revolutions succeeded and others failed. But I think it's also empowering in a strange way. Kevin: Empowering? How? Michael: Because it argues that the best way to improve people's lives isn't to hope for a 'good' leader or a better ideology. Good leaders are rare, and even they are subject to these rules. The only thing that reliably leads to better governance is changing the political math. The only thing that works is making the winning coalition so large, and the pool of potential replacements so big, that the leader has to provide good public policy—like clean water, safe streets, and good schools—to stay in power. Kevin: Because with a big coalition, you can't afford to give everyone a private jet. You have to provide things that benefit everyone, just to keep enough of them happy. Michael: That's what a democracy, at its best, is supposed to be. Not a system run by angels, but a system with incentives so widespread that even a self-interested leader is forced to act in the public's interest to survive. The book's ultimate message isn't that people are bad, but that incentives are powerful. Kevin: It forces you to look at politics like an engineer instead of a philosopher. You don't ask if a policy is 'good' or 'evil,' you ask: 'Who does this benefit? Who is in the winning coalition here?' Michael: Exactly. It gives you a new lens. It forces you to ask a really tough question: when you look at any leader, are you seeing their ideology, or are you just seeing the moves they're making to keep their coalition happy? Kevin: That's a powerful lens. And a challenging one. We'd love to hear what you all think. Does this theory change how you see politics in your own country, or even in your workplace? Let us know. Michael: This is Aibrary, signing off.

00:00/00:00