Aibrary Logo
Podcast thumbnail

The Dictator's Handbook

10 min

Why Bad Behavior is Almost Always Good Politics

Introduction

Narrator: In 2010, the small, impoverished city of Bell, California, became the center of a national scandal. Its city manager, Robert Rizzo, was earning nearly $800,000 a year, with other officials also pulling in exorbitant salaries. How could leaders in a town on the brink of bankruptcy justify paying themselves fortunes while their citizens struggled? Was this just a case of a few bad apples, or was something deeper at play? This very question lies at the heart of The Dictator's Handbook: Why Bad Behavior is Almost Always Good Politics by Bruce Bueno de Mesquita and Alastair Smith. The book argues that the actions of leaders like Rizzo are not exceptions but are, in fact, the logical outcomes of a universal set of political rules that govern anyone who wishes to gain and keep power.

Politics is a Game with Three Groups of Players

Key Insight 1

Narrator: To understand politics, one must first discard the notion that leaders rule alone. Whether a king, a CEO, or a democratic president, every leader depends on a base of support. The authors break down this political landscape into three distinct groups. First is the nominal selectorate, which includes every person who theoretically has a say in choosing the leader, like all registered voters in the United States. Within that group is the real selectorate, those who actually choose the leader, such as the voters who turn out on election day. Finally, and most importantly, is the winning coalition, the essential group of supporters whose backing is absolutely necessary for the leader to maintain power.

The size of these groups, particularly the winning coalition, dictates a leader's behavior. The story of Harvey Milk’s political career in San Francisco provides a perfect illustration. In 1975, when the city’s supervisors were elected in citywide contests, Milk lost. He needed a broad winning coalition from across the entire city, which he couldn't secure. However, in 1977, the rules changed to district-based elections. Suddenly, Milk only needed to win the support of his local neighborhood, the Castro. His winning coalition became much smaller and more concentrated, allowing him to win the election and become the first openly gay man elected to a major political office. The rules of the game changed, and so did the outcome.

The Five Rules for Ruling

Key Insight 2

Narrator: According to the authors, any leader who wants to survive must follow five basic rules. These rules are not about good governance but about pure political survival.

First, keep the winning coalition as small as possible. A smaller group of essentials is cheaper and easier to control. Second, keep the nominal selectorate as large as possible. This creates a large pool of potential replacements for any disloyal coalition members, keeping the current essentials in line. Third, control the flow of revenue. A leader must know where the money is and how to direct it to their supporters. Fourth, pay the winning coalition just enough to keep them loyal, but not a penny more. The goal is to ensure they are better off with the current leader than with any potential rival.

The final rule is the most cynical: never take money from the winning coalition’s pockets to make the people's lives better. A leader’s survival depends on the coalition, not the masses. Saddam Hussein was a master of these rules. Shortly after seizing power in 1979, he convened a meeting of the ruling Ba’ath Party. He had one official read a forced confession, who then named dozens of others in the room as co-conspirators. One by one, they were removed and executed. Saddam ruthlessly pruned his coalition, eliminating threats and ensuring the survivors knew their lives and fortunes depended entirely on his favor.

Corruption Isn't a Flaw, It's a Tool

Key Insight 3

Narrator: In systems with small winning coalitions, like dictatorships, public goods such as clean water, good roads, and quality schools are inefficient ways to maintain power. It is far more effective to reward the small group of essential supporters with private goods: cash, luxury contracts, and the freedom to be corrupt. The authors argue that for many leaders, corruption is not a problem to be solved but an essential political tool.

This dynamic isn't limited to national politics. Organizations like the International Olympic Committee (IOC) and FIFA have historically operated with very small winning coalitions—a handful of executives who decide which cities host the games. This structure incentivizes bidding cities to compete not on the quality of their facilities but on the private rewards they can offer to these few essential voters. This leads to scandals involving lavish gifts, lucrative jobs for relatives, and outright bribery. The system isn't broken; it's working exactly as designed for those in power. A leader who fails to provide these private rewards risks being replaced, as the mafia boss "Big" Paul Castellano discovered. When he shifted the Gambino crime family's focus away from the traditional rackets that enriched his soldiers, his coalition, led by John Gotti, had him assassinated.

Foreign Aid and War are Political Tools, Not Moral Crusades

Key Insight 4

Narrator: The logic of power extends to international relations. Foreign aid, the authors contend, is rarely about alleviating poverty. For donor countries, it's a tool to buy policy concessions from foreign leaders. A democratic leader might give aid to a dictator in exchange for access to oil or military basing rights, because these policies help the democratic leader satisfy their own winning coalition back home. For the recipient dictator, the aid is a source of revenue that doesn't require taxing their people, allowing them to fund their coalition and suppress dissent without needing to provide public goods. This is why aid often fails to improve lives and can entrench oppressive regimes.

War is viewed through the same political lens. Democrats and autocrats fight wars differently because their survival depends on different things. Democratic leaders, needing to satisfy a large coalition that bears the costs of war, must try their hardest to win. They commit vast resources because a loss could mean being voted out of office. Autocrats, however, are primarily concerned with rewarding their small coalition. They may start wars to plunder resources but are less committed to all-out victory if it threatens their hold on power or the flow of money to their cronies. The 1967 Six-Day War is a case in point. Israel, a democracy, fought with total commitment. Egypt, an autocracy, saw its generals more concerned with their own survival and loyalty to the regime than with battlefield success, leading to a swift and decisive defeat.

The Only Path to Better Governance is a Bigger Coalition

Key Insight 5

Narrator: If bad behavior is good politics, how can things ever improve? The authors argue that the only reliable path to better governance is to change the rules of the game by expanding the size of the winning coalition. When a leader needs a large number of people to stay in power, providing private rewards becomes too expensive and inefficient. The most effective way to satisfy a large coalition is through public goods that benefit everyone, such as the rule of law, public education, and healthcare.

This is why democracies, for all their flaws, generally produce better outcomes for their citizens. The solution is not to find more moral leaders, but to create a system where a leader's self-interest aligns with the public good. The authors point to the Green Bay Packers football team, the only community-owned, non-profit franchise in major American sports. With over 100,000 shareholders and a large board, no single individual can take control. The leadership must serve the broad interests of the fan-owners, resulting in one of the most loyal fanbases in sports. The lesson is clear: to fix politics, you must expand the circle of people whose support is essential to rule.

Conclusion

Narrator: The single most important takeaway from The Dictator's Handbook is that the logic of political survival trumps all other considerations, including ideology, morality, and the public good. Leaders do what keeps them in power, and their actions are dictated by the size of the coalition they depend on. A small coalition incentivizes corruption, oppression, and theft from the poor to give to the rich. A large coalition forces leaders to provide public goods and govern for the many.

This framework challenges us to look past the headlines and personalities that dominate political discourse. Instead of asking whether a leader is "good" or "evil," we should ask: Who keeps them in power, and what do those people want? By understanding these fundamental rules, we can better diagnose the problems in any system—from a nation-state to a corporate boardroom—and identify the only change that truly matters: making more people essential.

00:00/00:00